This week on the weblog I wish to take a quick detour into discussing historic coinage, significantly within the context of contemporary fantasy and roleplaying settings. Specifically, the notions I wish to deal with are first how did historical foreign money programs work by way of worth (what might you purchase with how a lot) after which second how typically had been individuals possible to make use of bodily foreign money in any respect? That is going to be a little bit of a ‘enjoyable one’ as a result of whereas we’ll discuss fairly a bit about how cash is utilized in historic societies, we’re going to loop again round to fantasy settings on the finish.
Transient Publish-Publication Notice: Somebody opted to throw what I can solely describe as a tantrum within the feedback, for causes that escape me. I’ve purged what I noticed, because it added nothing to the dialogue, although this will likely have orphaned some replies. If it begins up once more, bans will comply with; you might disagree, however you’ll do it in a well mannered, respectful, civil method when you are on my web site. If you wish to shout and name names, please take that the place it belongs, which is Twitter.
And the fantasy conceit that has sparked that is, in fact, the ever-present general-purpose RPG foreign money, ‘gold,’ understood to imply gold cash or gold items. Now in fact in lots of instances the trope-maker for ‘gold’ as the fundamental unit of foreign money is Dungeons and Dragons and folk will likely be fast to notice that D&D coinage has at all times included smaller denominations: copper, silver, gold and platinum items on a decimal-system valuation. And positive, that chart exists within the rule-book and a few frequent on a regular basis issues have their worth listed in cp or sp, however even an informal look at one thing just like the weapon desk reveals a ‘gp’ based mostly foreign money system. The three.5e weapon desk, for example, each weapon apart from sling bullets has its worth denominated in gold. 5e is a bit higher, however not a lot.
In the meantime, in Baldur’s Gate III, virtually definitely essentially the most widespread and culturally pervasive kind that D&D has taken in not less than the final decade – far extra individuals, I believe, have performed BG3 than have performed any type of D&D tabletop – compresses the system down neatly to simply the only foreign money kind: gold. As did Neverwinter Nights earlier than it. Likewise, the Elder Scrolls video games, together with Elder Scrolls On-line and Skyrim have a single foreign money, referred to as ‘gold,’ represented in sport by very clearly gold cash.

(Credit score the place credit score is due: Obsidian’s Eora, the universe the place Pillars of Eternity takes place, dodges this drawback: each tradition has its personal foreign money and also you see them repeatedly as loot. The sport then denominates all of them in a copper foreign money unit of account, which is definitely lots like how the sestertius (a copper-alloy coin) is utilized in Roman accounting. As we’re going to see, the important thing right here isn’t simply ‘have currencies apart from gold cash’ but additionally ‘have some sense of how huge a unit of account a gold coin goes to be’ and Eora is likely one of the few settings that appears to have absorbed, appropriately, that even a single gold coin is such a big unit of cash as to be ineffective in most circumstances.)
So throughout a variety of fantasy merchandise – video games, movies, books and settings – this tends to be system: ‘gold,’ by which is supposed gold cash, are the usual unit of account, values are reckoned in gold and when cash must be proven, it’s sometimes bodily gold cash. If there are smaller items, we don’t see them typically. Crucially, characters in dialogue will typically use ‘gold’ or the names of gold coin denominations (‘crowns,’ ‘sovereigns,’ and many others. proven within the fiction to be gold cash) as synonyms for cash. Generally there’s a bigger unit, virtually invariably ‘platinum,’ which can also be a reasonably foolish foreign money to have on condition that other than some proof that it was alloyed with gold in Egypt and South America (maybe unknowingly so), nobody is utilizing platinum or conscious of its existence earlier than the 1500s.
And, as you’ll have guessed, there are some issues with this: functionally nobody used gold in any quantity in every-day transactions within the historical or medieval Mediterranean (or most different locations!), as a result of a gold coin at virtually any dimension was such an monumental financial unit as to be unsuited to most transactions. That in flip conceals a number of the sharpness of wealth and sophistication distinctions in pre-modern society in ways in which flatten and admittedly ‘modernize’ these societies. And it additionally misunderstands the financial programs of those societies, as a result of it doesn’t perceive what kind of transactions individuals would even wish to use cash for, which additional flattens and modernizes these societies.
As an alternative, what I wish to do is lay out a few actual historic foreign money programs – we’re going to take a look at historical Greek and Roman foreign money, in addition to the medieval pound/shilling/pence (or livre/sou/dinier) system – and discuss how they’re denominated and why.

Behind, clockwise: an Attic tetradrachma (c. 449BC), a Roman denarius (41 BC), an Aeginetan drachma (c. 550 BC) and an early Roman denarius (c. 115 BC).
However first, as at all times, I too recognize cash and at all times needed to take up amassing historical cash (which, I ought to notice, could be legally acquired at costs attainable by mortals, as a result of we now have so many – simply ensure you’re getting one thing with correct provenance; any respected supplier will cheerfully provide you with this). If you wish to assist me to take up costly hobbies, you’ll be able to help this challenge on Patreon! Amici of the weblog at Patreon get month-to-month updates on my analysis progress (or lack thereof), whereas patrons on the Matres et Patres Conscripti degree additionally get to vote on future matters. If you need updates at any time when a brand new put up seems, you’ll be able to click on beneath for e-mail updates, or you’ll be able to comply with me on Bluesky (@bretdevereaux.bsky.social) or Twitter (@BretDevereaux) or (much less continuously) Mastodon (@bretdevereaux@historians.social) for updates as to new posts in addition to my occasional historical historical past, overseas coverage or army historical past musings; I’m in all probability extra lively lately on Bluesky than Twitter.
Introducing Our Currencies
Globally, each the concept of foreign money (by which I imply an summary notional unit of worth) and coinage (by which I imply a bodily object representing that unit of worth) had been invented in a couple of place at a couple of time. These are, I ought to notice, distinct concepts and it’s the summary unit of account which comes first, lengthy earlier than (and we imply centuries earlier than) somebody will get the brilliant concept of utilizing particular objects to signify these notional items.
That mentioned, all the coinage programs of the broader Mediterranean world appear to spark from a single supply, the event of coinage within the kingdom of Lydia within the seventh century. The best way to know these cash is that this: these societies had already been utilizing metals – measured by weight – to outline summary, notional items of worth for accounting functions and in some instances bodily transactions. That is essential to notice: cash within the summary sense (and debt, for that matter) come first and coinage comes second. In apply, what a coin was merely a pre-measured quantity of treasured steel, stamped by the authorities to attest that it was the quantity it claimed to be.
Notice the rapid implication that has: the coin is barely well worth the steel it has in it. In the event you cut back the burden of the coin or dilute the dear steel in it (by alloying it with baser metals), you’ve got lowered the worth of the coin (and possibly dedicated a critical crime, except you’re the state). This meant that whereas states might get cute and attempt to stretch the treasury by issuing cash with much less treasured steel in them (referred to as ‘debasement’) within the long-run this successfully led to inflation: as people realized there was much less silver or gold or no matter within the cash, they’d elevate costs accordingly. However we needn’t get into all the complexities of minting and debasement right here.
What I wish to do first right here is introduce our foreign money programs and what they’re referred to as, so we now have that readily available for after we focus on how they’re valued and used.
The primary coinage in Lydia doesn’t appear to have penetrated very far in society – the cash appear (the proof isn’t nice) to have principally been used for big transactions, long-distance commerce, that type of factor. As an alternative, it’s in Greece, which adopts coinage from the Lydians, the place we first see cash penetrating deep into society and turning into a normal method to do enterprise. Now every Greek polis issued its personal foreign money (besides Sparta), so as a substitute of only one set of ‘Greek foreign money’ you had an entire mess of various polis foreign money on completely different weight and purity requirements. That mentioned, profitable currencies tended to be imitated and so a ‘customary’ (which different Greek currencies would possibly deviate from) emerged: Attic coinage, the principally extensively used, ultimately turns into that baseline.

The Attic foreign money customary was based mostly – as practically all Greek currencies had been – on the drachma (shortened by numismatists to ‘drachm’) a silver coin that weighed round 4.3g and was concerning the dimension of an American dime (however a bit thicker). 4 drachma made the aptly named tetradrachma, a silver coin of 17.2g, which was concerning the dimension of an American quarter (however thicker and about thrice as heavy). In the meantime a drachma could possibly be cut up into six oboloi – invariably referred to as obols in English. The obol was, apparently, initially a rod of instrument steel (copper, bronze and even iron), which can have derived out of merely utilizing a forge-ready billet as foreign money (though those we discover don’t appear to have been used that method). Nevertheless, by the classical interval, the obol had grow to be a normal very small silver coin, tariffed at 1/sixth of a drachma and thus having a silver mass of simply 0.7g or so; they are usually round c. 8mm throughout, so a bit lower than half the scale of the smallest American coin (the dime).

The Greeks additionally had some bigger ‘items of account’ which weren’t minted as cash, however had been utilized in accounting to specific giant portions of cash. Thus 100 drachmae was a mina (435g of silver), and 6,000 drachmae was a expertise (26.1kg on the Attic customary); notice that each the mina and expertise had been items of weight, so you’ll be able to have a mina or a expertise of one thing apart from silver, however in accounting, it’s at all times silver-weight that’s being calculated as worth. It is a monometallic customary: mainly all the foreign money is in silver, there’s little or no gold coinage in any respect (sometimes some electrum coinage and we do see gold cash in huge denominations within the Hellenistic). Now all of that is for the Classical/Hellenistic Attic customary; once more there have been many requirements and so they modified over time, however this overview will do us for now.
So once more: 6 obols = 1 drachma = 1/4th tetradrachma = 1/a hundredth mina = 1/6000th expertise.
Subsequent up is Roman coinage and right here we’re going to make use of the foreign money system because it existed within the reign of Augustus. The Romans decide up coinage comparatively late; there are some experiments with huge ‘ol bronze foreign money (the aes grave) but it surely’s actually with the Second Punic Conflict (218-201) that the Romans start minting in earnest, initially on a bimetallic customary (silver and bronze) after which by Augustus’ day on a trimetallic customary (bronze, silver and gold), although actually solely the latter two metals are supporting the worth of the coin. Now in case you are questioning, “wait, how does a multi-metallic customary work if all the metals have ‘floating’ (market decided) values?” And the reply is that the actual fact that the state ensures the problem of coinage on a set alternate anchors the metals to a set alternate price, which principally works as a result of whereas steel costs did fluctuate considerably over lengthy durations, the fundamental relationship whereby gold was extra treasured than silver, which was extra treasured than copper, bronze or brass, remained regular.

The Roman equal to the drachma was the denarius, a silver coin of – by Augustus – about 3.9g (it had been 4.5g in 211), which is a close to good match for the drachma. The denarius could possibly be damaged into 4 sestertii (sing. sestertius); this had been a small silver coin within the Republic, however by Augustus, it was an enormous ol’ brass coin, round 25g or so and about 32mm throughout (so a 3rd or so wider than an American quarter). One sixteenth of a denarius was the as (pl. asses), the Roman penny, a copper coin of 10.9g. Going the opposite method, 25 denarii made a single aureus, a gold coin of about 7.75g.
So once more: 16 asses = 4 sestertii = 1denarius = 1/twenty fifth aureus.

Not like the Greeks, the Romans don’t have jumbo-sized unminted accounting items. As an alternative, most Roman accounts are totaled in sestertii, with the fashionable abbreviation HS (soo 100HS is 100 sestertii or 25 denarii or 1 aureus).
Earlier than we transfer on to the Center Ages, I wish to make yet one more notice to keep away from people making an comprehensible and predictable error. We’ve a doc from the traditional world, Diocletian’s Edict on Most Costs, which has an entire mess of most costs for items and providers in it. It is a supply for use with care: Diocletian is issuing the edict as a result of his personal carelessness with the money-system has sparked runaway inflation and he’s attempting (unsuccessfully) to repair it with worth controls. By Diocletian’s day (even earlier than he sparked runaway inflation) the denarius had misplaced mainly all of its silver content material and was thus of far decrease worth than it had been pre-235, so the costs within the Edict are already a lot larger – probably orders of magnitude larger – than first century costs. Furthermore, it’s an Edict on most costs, not regular costs, which can both imply that Diocletian is setting the costs absurdly low (to curb the inflation) or absurdly excessive (as a result of they’re most costs, in spite of everything); there’s no motive to suppose it even displays common costs on the time. So: Diolcetian’s Value Edict must be used very fastidiously and completely should not be used with first century Roman coinage in thoughts. In apply, nearly the one helpful factor to do with the Value Edict is to check its costs internally (that’s, to different costs in the identical doc).
Now for medieval European foreign money, issues get difficult, as a result of the European Center Ages are outlined by fragmentation and so you’ve got a number of tiny polities probably issuing foreign money on completely different requirements. However in Western Europe, one frequent system had been these derived from the Carolingian coinage system, put in place by Charlemagne within the 790s and it’s common to see medieval costs denominated in these items, each on the time and in fashionable scholarship. Importantly, these are the items utilized by the very talked-about Medieval Value Listing put collectively by Kenneth Hodges, so its price treating them right here.
This method notionally had three items: the livre (or pound, from Latin libra, “pound,” abbreviated L or £), the sou (or shilling, from Latin solidus, a late Roman coin, abbreviated s) and the denier (or penny/pence, from Latin denarius, abbreviated d); please notice that whereas Charlemagne is reusing the names of Roman cash, these cash had undergone huge debasement through the years and so seemed nothing like their earlier Roman equivalents.
As an alternative the system was a monmetallic silver-standard: one livre was 408g of silver, whereas a sou was 1/twentieth of a livre (20.4g) and a denier was 1/240th of a livre (1.7g). In apply, solely the smallest coin, the denier, was extensively minted.
So £1 (or 1 L = pound) = 20 s (shillings) and 1 s (shilling) = 12 d (pence).
Now what makes this method…thrilling…is that within the subsequent fragmentation of the Carolingian Empire, everyone seems to be utilizing this method however minting their very own cash, resulting in completely different weights and thrilling quantities of debasement. Gresham’s Legislation is the precept, well-established, that if in case you have ‘good’ (extra pure, heavier) and ‘unhealthy’ (much less pure or lighter) foreign money each circulating, ‘unhealthy cash drives out good,’ as a result of individuals hoard the nice cash and use the unhealthy cash; this additional sophisticated the drift of the pound-shilling-pence system off of its notional weight customary. By 1262, the commonest French livre, the livre tournois had declined to simply 80.8 grams (by 1726, it was simply 4.5g…getting us mainly again to the drachma!).

That mentioned, as Europe received richer, these notional items of account (significantly the pound) which had been by no means minted got here into use and this provides us an ungainly image of the problems of this method the place the precise foreign money weight had grow to be so indifferent from its nominal worth. In France, the livre tournois, notionally 80.8g of silver, was minted as a gold coin within the 1300s of about 3.76g. Within the 1480s, the English start minting a gold sovereign coin equal to £1 – by which they imply an precise pound sterling; it was 15.55g gold coin. Now some fast math and that type of is smart: 15.55g of gold representing c. 400g of silver (a c. 1:25 ratio) and three.76g of gold representing simply 80.8g of silver (1:21.5 ratio), however in fact precisely what a pound was had modified drastically, although I ought to notice that so far as I do know, it was the English who had been out of step right here. Different fashionable late medieval gold currencies had been the gold ducat (3.5g or so) and the gold florin (3.499g) and we will see these sit fairly near the French livre tournois.

So if you end up taking a look at Kenneth Hodges Medieval Value Listing, it’s best to know each that the foreign money programs in use listed below are fluctuating fairly a bit, making worth comparisons throughout dates difficult, particularly somewhere else however that broadly talking you would possibly say that within the 1300s and past (the place most of his knowledge is from) a livre is round 80g of silver, a sou is thus round 4g (conveniently near our drachma and denarius) and a pence is round simply 0.33g in worth.

I do know that was lots however I needed to stroll by way of it so that you’ll perceive the subsequent bit – even if you happen to didn’t get all the particulars there – for the important thing conclusion which is:
A Gold Coin Is an Absurdly Giant Unit of Cash
For normal individuals, not less than.
Each time historical or medieval coinage or foreign money comes up, the query people at all times wish to ask is, “what’s that in right now’s {dollars}?“ And I completely perceive this query, as a result of if it could possibly be answered – spoilers, it will probably’t be – it will present the questioner with a direct benchmark of worth to use.
And the reply is simply: it isn’t. The issue is each that the worth of commodities modifications over time, however specifically that the second agricultural revolution and the commercial revolutions so wildly shifted the values of commodities as to make any potential translation of historical or medieval foreign money values into fashionable ones deceptive. I might calculate, for example, based mostly on labor time, making 1 day of labor equal to the minimal wage equal (a denarius is price $230), or by steel weight, so {that a} gram of silver is the same as its present commodity worth (an unskilled Roman would possibly earn c. $4 a day) or by grain equal (an unskilled Roman would possibly make $1.62 per day) – all of these solutions are wildly completely different and equally unsuitable, regardless that I’m assessing the identical knowledge level: {that a} denarius was an affordable wage for a day of labor within the first century. I’ve ended up concluding that $1.62 = $4 = $230; clearly one thing has gone very unsuitable! The incomes and consumption patterns of historical and medieval individuals are sufficiently completely different to our personal to make any direct comparability ineffective and misleading.
However there are different methods to consider the worth of cash (and specifically coinage) within the lives of on a regular basis individuals: by considering by way of how a lot labor it took to get that cash and the way a lot it might purchase.
Now we needs to be clear that wages and costs fluctuated prior to now simply as they do now. Nevertheless, we will use historic worth knowledge – which just about at all times comes within the type of ‘snapshot’ costs that will or is probably not ‘regular’ (certainly, costs typically get cited in our sources exactly as a result of they’re unrepresentative excessive or low) to get a way of not less than the fundamental order of magnitude that issues may cost.
For the traditional world, from the Classical interval by way of to the early Roman Imperial interval, we even have one actually handy rule of thumb that reveals up in a bunch of locations: a drachma or denarius (keep in mind, these are equally sized silver cash) a day was a good wage; not a typical wage, thoughts you, however a good one. Athenian citizen rowers within the Athenian navy – who, to be clear, are having fun with the benefit of with the ability to vote themselves good wages from a treasury full of tribute from subordinated poleis – had been paid a drachma a day (Thuc. 3.17.3-4). A single drachma per day additionally seems to have been the usual wage for mercenaries within the Greek East through the Hellenistic interval, and the pay of the Roman equites – the cavalry drawn from the upper-classes – within the military of the Roman Republic was more-or-less a denarius a day (Polyb. 6.39.12). Lastly, famously the Parable of the Staff within the Winery (Matthew 20:1-16) offers the wages of the employees as a denarius for a full day’s work, a beneficiant however not totally unreasonable wage.
(Additionally, notice how delicate these wages are to political economies: Athenian rowers are selecting to pay themselves fairly generously (as they vote for such issues), whereas Roman citizen-soldiers (by definition, each troopers and tax-payers, assidui) decide to pay themselves rather a lot much less (2 obols = 3 asses a day) – being compensated extra in honor and their political position within the Republic. Who you’re, politically and socially, issues rather a lot for the way effectively you receives a commission or if you happen to receives a commission in any respect.)
As an alternative, what I wish to give attention to is what an infinite unit a denarius or a drachma already is, possible considerably greater than the typical every day wage. Now, as a result of the productiveness of pre-modern economies is so low, that’s lots lower than what the every day wage can be in a contemporary industrial financial system, however its nonetheless a big quantity to the employee who earns it. Grain appears to have run anyplace from 2-3HS per modius (a Roman dry measure, about 6.75kg) exterior of actually huge cities with larger costs. A modius of grain is near per week’s price of meals (round 22,500 energy) for an grownup human, in order that denarius should purchase near week’s price of a household’s main foodstuff in most components of the Roman world.
(If you’re doing the maths and considering that this feels like a price of pay inconsistent with the poverty you’ve been informed most individuals lived with within the historical world, the reply is that wage labor was scarce and intermittent. You may rapidly see how a household whose adults can solely get paying work just a few days every week can be perpetually teetering on the sting of sustainability. That’s why a regular wage from one thing like service within the fleet or mercenary work (or jury pay in Athens!) was so helpful to the poor.)
So a denarius or a drachma isn’t a unit so huge that no regular individual would ever use it, however it’s a large enough unit that one is hardly going to make use of it casually: principally you’d be utilizing obols or asses for on a regular basis transactions and maybe escape a denarius or two for one thing like per week’s price of grain or probably fairly just a few denarii for sturdy items like a brand new tunic. Even a barely bigger unit, like a tetradrachma would possibly nonetheless be helpful for a reasonably chunky buy, and you’ll think about a day-laborer engaged on per week lengthy challenge getting a tetradrachma and maybe some change on the finish of the job.
However what is a coin of such giant worth {that a} regular individual isn’t going to make use of it? The aureus, the usual Roman gold coin. That coin, in spite of everything, is price twenty-five denarii, which (given the irregularity of wage labor) might be greater than most laborers made in a month. Heck, skilled Roman troopers – full time citizen-professionals – within the first century made 900HS (=225 denarii) per 12 months, so a single aureus is greater than their gross month-to-month pay (75 sestertii in comparison with 100 sestertii for that aureus). You may think about non-elite transactions that might be this massive – there’s a pill from Vindolanda (dates starting from 85 to 130 AD) which notes the acquisition of 90 kilos of iron for 32 denarii, for example – however you must think about even the service provider would relatively have 32 silver cash he can spend relatively than one gigantic gold coin he’s going to must pay a money-lender to interrupt (additionally in these tablets, for comparability, a entire dwell hen‘s worth is a bit lower than half a denarius, for reference, however equally a saddle-cloth goes for 12 denarii by itself).
If we seek the advice of the traditional Medieval Value Listing, we see fairly comparable breakdowns. Every day wages for a talented thatcher (primarily a roofing specialist) vary from Second-6d (=pence, you’ll recall) per day (the change possible as a lot the product of inflation as improved buying energy); his much less expert ‘mate’ makes anyplace from 1d to 4d. Retaining in thoughts that by this level the sou/shilling represents the same quantity of silver to the denarius or the drachma and is 12d, our thatcher is making that a lot each 3-6 days. Some receives a commission a much less; a set of 14th century wages from the record, kitchen servants make 2s-4s (24-48d) per 12 months, although admittedly that’s in England the place – as you’ll notice above – the worth of the coinage has been extra fastidiously defended.
As soon as once more, we see that who you had been might matter lots: from his 14th century wages, knights are incomes 2-4s (24-48d) per day, whereas armored infantry earn simply 6d per day, so the knight banneret will get paid eight instances his infantryman to march in the identical military. However that’s not the underside! The underside are the ‘Welsh infantry’ paid solely Second per day, a 3rd as a lot as the upper standing armored infantry and 1/twenty fourth what the knights are getting. After all, a part of the pay differential is that these combatants are anticipated to convey their very own package and the socio-economic elite has introduced heavier (costly!) armor and expects to be compensated accordingly.
However I wish to notice what nobody is getting paid: any livre or kilos! Even the knight banneret‘s every day wage is 1/fifth a livre. Certainly, only a few issues which aren’t clearly signalled as extravagances for the elite have their worth denominated in kilos. Full armors, presumably plate (within the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries), are priced at £8 and £3 (and alter, in each instances), and a twelfth century mail hauberk is listed at 100s (so £5). These possible signify the most effective sensible safety obtainable in these durations and so they’re priced in single digit numbers of kilos, which as famous above are equal to or very shut to those gold cash (the livre tournais, ducat or florin). The issues that do have prices in £ are issues like buildings and costly objects for elites (court docket robes, books, conflict horses, the annual wage of a priest (simply £4 13s 4d a 12 months!)).
And that brings us to our first main conclusion: in most pre-industrial settings, a gold coin of any dimension is an impractical unit of alternate for ‘common individuals.’ As an alternative, what your aurei or ducats or florins are for is facilitating the storage is substantial quantities of wealth and enabling large-scale transactions by retailers and elites, both of bulk items or luxurious items. They may additionally, in fact, operate notionally as items of account (just like the Greek expertise or the Carolingian livre). Each day foreign money was virtually invariably minted in silver or copper (or copper-alloys).
However there’s a second implication right here which goes to matter for the subsequent part, which you’ll have already observed in a number of the costs and values being quoted: in these pre-modern, agrarian societies the financial divide between common individuals and the rich elite was huge and functionally unbridgeable (and the coinage was designed for the elite first). In consequence, typically the rich landholding elite in these societies had entry to total lessons of products which may merely not be obtainable beneath virtually any circumstances to the commons, as a result of they required portions of cash that may be comparatively trivial to the elite however which had been unobtainable for the lots. Blowing £5 to equip a heavy infantryman was not an enormous expense for a baron who would possibly usher in ~ £500 yearly, however for a standard laborer or peasant, £5 was going to be solidly out of attain.
All That Glisters
So if it doesn’t make a lot sense to reward your Dungeons and Dragons adventuring celebration (let’s be sincere why we’re all nonetheless studying this) with gold, what ought to you reward them with?
The comparatively straightforward reply can be to rename your foreign money ‘silver,’ calculate assuming one or two silver cash is an affordable wage for preventing, adventuring or different high-skill or high-risk professions after which retariff your whole different costs accordingly, maintaining in thoughts that these are societies had been manufactured items are very costly, however unspecialized agricultural labor could be very low cost. And that’s not an totally unreasonable factor to do. While you’re at it, comparatively few languages use ‘gold’ as a synecdoche for ‘cash,’ however lots of languages use their phrase for ‘silver’ that method: Latin argentum, Greek ἀργύριον, plata in Spanish, argent in French and so forth.
However a part of the rationale these coinage programs work they method they do is that they operated in societies wherein loads of financial exercise was non-monetary or not less than, non-coinage. And right here, we should always return to our ‘cash’ vs. ‘foreign money’ or ‘coinage:’ keep in mind, cash got here first. So let’s say you reside in a small group – like a peasant village working beneath a giant landholder’s manor – and you must transact some issues, however you don’t have any precise silver as a result of cash are scarce and worthwhile (and being a subsistence farmer, you develop most of what you want your self), how do you do it? Effectively, a method is to do it ‘on accounts’ – you want wool and so when the shepherds come down from the hills, you commerce for a few of their wool through the shearing with a household and each you and so they make a psychological notice that you just owe them for the wool. You would possibly specific that quantity of debt in silver (as a unit weight – see how we get to coinage as a pre-measured weight of silver?) however there’s no motive to measure out silver (even if you happen to had any) since you see these people yearly and subsequent time they’ll ask you for some grain and so forth.
Notice that this isn’t the identical because the idea of ‘barter’ – there’s, the truth is, a notional ‘cash’ middleman, it’s simply not a bodily coin or invoice, its expressed as an account, a purely notional unit of worth.
In the meantime, that small farmer additionally owes ‘taxes’ or rents to the state or the Massive Man who owns their land – the road between ‘rents’ and ‘taxes’ in pre-modern states is very fuzzy – are additionally more likely to be paid in form. What meaning is as a substitute of paying in coin, a sure slice of the harvest or a certain quantity of grain or a sure numbers of days of corvée labor is owed. That obligation too might have a notional financial worth, enabling fines or repayments for providers to be docked towards tax legal responsibility, as soon as once more eradicating a lot of the necessity for a bodily foreign money.
Lastly, you even have a ‘present financial system’ which is totally non-monetary (virtually by definition). We’ve talked about one type of this: the horizontal ‘banqueting your neighbors’ financial system whereby small farmers create and preserve non-monetarily outlined relationships of financial dependence: I banquet you when my harvest is sweet, so that you assist me out when it’s unhealthy and vice versa. You may as well have vertical relationships of this kind: the Massive Man, you’ll recall, is amassing plenty of rents, but additionally has entry to much more capital – instruments, work animals, surplus labor and so forth. Most of that capital goes to enter his personal pursuits (politics or conflict, normally), however typically the customs in these societies are that a few of it are ‘gifted’ again – so, for example, it was typical for the proprietor of a manor in a manorial medieval system to banquet the village on explicit days (typically the times the place he collected rents). Entry to these instruments, capital and sources might thus probably be ‘gifted’ downward, which could matter, as a single village would possibly effectively not create ample financial demand to make use of sure specialised craftworkers (blacksmiths, for example) whose merchandise are nonetheless crucial – however the Massive Man’s a lot bigger financial footprint can help such a employee. And naturally the Massive Males additionally have their very own horizontal Massive Man to Massive Man present economies, which you’ll be able to see within the giving of elite items in works just like the Iliad or Beowulf.
The result’s that the fundamental regular situation of the pre-industrial countryside is mostly non-coinage (if not non-monetary). “Monetizing” the countryside (an ungainly time period which actually means ‘currency-izing’ the countryside) is usually one thing states must deliberately do. The rationale a state would possibly wish to do that is easy: the massive benefit coinage has is to make transactions with unfamiliar events (individuals you’ll be able to’t belief to pay you again later) simpler and the state typically does loads of enterprise with unfamiliar events, particularly if it operates at scale. Consequently, it’s typically good for the state to have the ability to gather taxes in silver in order that it will probably pay for items and wages in silver. That is, in fact, very true if the soldiery the state depends on expects to receives a commission in silver: one of many enormous challenges that the successors of Alexander the Nice confronted was that they inherited a military (the Macedonian one) that anticipated wages paid in silver cash, however topic economies (in Egypt, Anatolia, Syria, Mesopotamia and the Iranian Plateau) which weren’t meaningfully monetized (once more, which means ‘not utilizing loads of coinage;’ sure the time period is awkward, however it’s the time period used). For the Seleucids, the answer was to create market facilities (normally cities or colonies of Greek army settlers accustomed to repeatedly utilizing coinage), which might purchase up agricultural surplus in order that the native populace could possibly be taxed in coin (after which minting a ton of cash to flow into on this system); for the Ptolemies, the answer was really to maintain Egypt a principally closed foreign money system, however to promote the grain taxed in form overseas and use that silver income (reminted on the lighter Ptolemaic customary) to pay their troopers.
That mentioned, within the pre-modern world, comprehensively ‘coined’ economies exist however are the exception. If you’re questioning the place such economies are usually (on your fantasy worldbuilding), they’re virtually at all times city, as a result of it’s cities, with their giant populations of non-farmers, that create the natural demand for markets in bulk staples for the frequent inhabitants of the town to purchase with the small-denomination cash they’ll earn from irregular wage-labor.
Outdoors these cities, nevertheless, the Massive Males magnates within the countryside – ‘feudal’ lords, giant rentier landholders or tribal Massive Males – aren’t normally receiving cash in rents, however bulk agricultural items. They can promote these items to get silver with which to purchase issues, however they’ll equally decide to help producers of their households out of the rents (in agricultural items) they obtain. That is, for example, the traditional mannequin of the Bronze Age ‘redistribution’ or ‘palace’ economies: rents in agricultural items circulate into the palace, which doesn’t normally promote them, however relatively makes use of them to help specialist producers, whose items are then pushed again down as items or entitlements (for example, the king graciously equipping his soldiery with weapons).
Rewarding Your Dungeons and Dragons Occasion
And so we will finally loop again round to the preliminary quandry, the tyranny of ‘gold’ as a normal reward on your fictional adventuring celebration in a Dungeons and Dragons (or comparable) marketing campaign or setting.
As you’ll be able to inform, mainly nobody goes at hand a celebration gold for defeating a bunch of goblin raiders or getting that Aboleth out of the lake. However as a result of completely different varieties of individuals in several pre-modern economies have interaction with coinage and cash in several methods, they’ll in all probability attempt to pay in other ways.
The inhabitants most probably to wish to pay with cash are the burghers (townsfolk): as famous above, city facilities which have plenty of non-farmers and populations too giant for everybody to simply know everybody else are perfect for the usage of coinage and are usually the place coinage catches on most rapidly and utterly. There’s thus one thing of an irony: the city will wish to pay you in cash, which you can be greatest in a position to spend…within the city’s market. Bear in mind: comparatively little of this coinage is circulating again into the countryside (except you’ve got a state extracting rents and taxes in coin!), however then in fact the city is more likely to have all kinds of producers completely happy to transform your fairly silver cash into stuff you really need. That’s effectively sufficient, you hardly wish to journey with plenty of coinage anyway: the burden is trivial and the cash are liable to get stolen in any occasion.
The villagers for a small rural village would possibly be capable of scrape up some silver cash – they in all probability hold some silver for coping with retailers, craftsmen and so forth – however that could be a restricted provide and so they’d a lot relatively pay in one thing they’ve in abundance: meals (and different agricultural items). That will appear foolish, however keep in mind wanting above how giant a piece of a employee’s common earnings simply getting meals and lodging could possibly be: an enormous feast after which a two-weeks provide of grains (as a lot as you’ll be able to carry, successfully) might really be a reasonably respectable chunk of worth. In the event that they want one thing with a better value-density, they could really supply the opposite factor produced repeatedly in households: textiles. Good material was worthwhile, moveable and helpful; within the 14th century one worth datapoint we now have put top quality wool at 5s per yard. After all there are going to be actual limits to how a lot a rural village may even pay on these phrases: for any bigger drawback, they’ll must depend on their vertical contacts (in apply, they’d have relied on these first) and go as much as the Massive Man.
Now the Massive Man on the hill, just like the burghers within the city, has sources: he will pay for army service. Certainly, in a way, his job is paying for army service: he holds his place in no small half as a result of he takes the excess manufacturing of his rural tenants/topics (extracted by way of rents and taxes) and makes use of it to pay for army drive with which he holds and enforces his declare to rents and taxes, each towards any peasant’s dream of independence, however equally towards different Massive Males. And assuming it is a setting the place coinage has been invented, the Massive Man definitely has entry to a ample quantity to pay merely pay in money for providers rendered coping with that Owlbear his retainers saved failing to trace.
However the Massive Man would in all probability relatively ‘pay’ your adventurers in a different way. In spite of everything, do not forget that the Massive Man is operating a enterprise which converts agricultural surplus (extracted in rents) into army energy (males, horses, weapons, armor) and legitimacy (typically conferred with extravagant items: jewellery and such). So whereas he might merely transact enterprise and pay you in silver and ship you in your method, it will be lots simpler to compensate you with what he has as effectively: he would possibly present you a sword or set of armor from his armory, or a horse from his stables.
That present isn’t simply simpler for him, it comes with broader social implications that are additionally higher for him and for you. Whereas fee in cash may not incur any nice obligation, the alternate of items right here – you’ve got solved an issue, he has given you one thing in return – creates a social obligation, a bond between you, particularly if the worth of the present exceeds the worth of the service. You are actually obligated to assist out once more, sooner or later, ought to he ask, out of ‘gratitude’ for the ‘present’ (and for such providers, you’ll obtain extra ‘items’). In the meantime, keep in mind up high about how a lot one’s place within the political financial system issues for the way effectively one is paid – simply being a extra essential type of individual in these societies might transform the way you had been compensated and thus your station in life?
Effectively, in contrast to just a few cash, these items can change who you’re: a person with a powerful arm is a peasant; a person with a powerful arm, gifted mail and a weapon is a man-at-arms, whose station entitles them to higher therapy. That very same man, gifted a horse and a lance, by the Massive Man is a knight (or substitute the culturally acceptable moniker for minor mounted army aristocrat). That’s nice for you – much better than just some cash that make you merely a momentarily wealthy peasant – but additionally nice for the Massive Man who simply purchased himself a minor army aristocrat (keep in mind: you’re obligated to be pleased about his generosity and to reply if he calls), minted out of shops of weapons he was maintaining for simply such an event. Certainly, Tacitus describes how the present of weapons was what enabled a younger man to take a full place in public life amongst Germanic tribes – a customized that we see echoes of in different non-state communities and so might assume did, the truth is, happen – “However it’s uncommon for anybody to put on arms earlier than the civitas has acknowledged their proper to them. Then earlier than the council, one of many principes or a father or a relative equips a younger man with a spear and a defend. These are to them what the toga is to us: the primary honor of a youth.”
The opposite factor, in fact, that the Massive Man has in abundance is land and peasants (probably serfs, probably tenants, probably slaves). Even higher than a present of status-changing weapons, he would possibly supply as a substitute to take you into his family, pulling you into his everlasting retinue, with a promise of upkeep (meals, clothes, tools) equal to your new, elevated station. Alternately, he would possibly attempt to ‘settle’ you to ascertain a everlasting, lasting obligation: offer you some land and peasants in alternate for a proper expectation of service (an oath of vassalage or homage in a medieval context). Whereas there’s an inclination to consider this by way of grand estates, such settlements could possibly be ‘comparatively’ small: Hellenistic army settlers in Ptolemaic Egypt typically received plots that had been 25-30 arourai (17-20 acres) for soldiers – hardly a large property, however sufficient that the rents alone might preserve the infantryman and his family with out having to do any precise farming himself. In not less than some societies, such a present may not even essentially imply the top of adventuring; in medieval European vassalage-based polities, it was typically potential to owe service to a couple of liege and freelance some army exercise on the facet (although extra successfully centralized states are extra jealous about their army manpower).
To wrap up: in some methods pre-modern economies could possibly be extra advanced than ours, as a result of they hadn’t but lowered practically all transactions all the way down to financial alternate. ‘Gold’ isn’t going to be terribly helpful in most contexts, however even the place extra frequent silver cash can be found, its typically going to be in an people curiosity to as a substitute embed themselves into economies of patronage and gift-exchange that are non-monetary or to know transactions as abstractly financial, with out bodily gold or silver altering arms. However a very powerful items and funds in these societies had been ones that modified an individual’s standing, which might typically be so simple as a present of correct weapons or a horse, maybe appropriately witnessed by different elites.
And that type of factor: working one’s method up from serving to peasants who can’t pay with something greater than an excellent meal and provides to the street as much as items that come freighted with deep social significance and alter an individual’s very standing in society – that’s a a lot richer tapestry to weave a narrative out of than ‘gold.’
And likewise, and I have to stress this once more: gold cash had been monumental items of foreign money nobody used each day. If I’ve to pay 100 ‘gold’ for a sword, that sword had higher be jewel-encrusted, gilt, fabricated from the best metal imported from India.